Skip to main content
Log in

Rights, equity, and economic efficiency

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Summary and conclusions

The Adelman-Morris premise that economic development and equity are incompatible is not supported by the evidence of a strong relationship between equality of rights and the income distribution. The premise that equity requires the denial of individual rights and the affirmation of state control is an oxymoron. What has been overlooked in the literature on growth and equity is the effect of the rights structure on both economic efficiency and on the income distribution. The evidence is that free societies have much larger shares of income going to the middle 60 percent of the distribution than is observed in societies where men are not free to choose. In politically open societies compared to politically closed regimes the share of income to the middle three quintiles is: Q2 (10.7 vs. 8.0), Q3 (16.0 vs. 11.5), and Q4 (22.9 vs. 17.9). In the aggregate the shares to the middle quintiles are 49.6 vs. 37.4. In nations that obey the rule of law compared to regimes in which the rights of the state relative to the individual are paramount the comparisons are: Q2 (11.2 vs. 7.4), Q3 (16.3 vs. 10.6), Q4 (23.0 vs. 17.3). Summing the three quintiles yields a comparison of 50.5 vs. 35.3. In countries that have private property, market allocation of resources, and minimum intervention by the state compared to command economies the shares of income to the middle quintiles are: Q2 (10.8 vs. 8.0), Q3 (16.0 vs. 11.1), and Q4 (22.8 vs. 17.7). Aggregated the shares of the middle class in regimes with high levels of economic liberty are 49.6 vs. 36.8 for regimes with restricted private economic rights.

Equally revealing as a matter of equity is the status of the poor and the rich in free and statist nations. The income share of the highest income group is much larger in nations that repress individual rights than in those where rights are protected. Averaging across the rights measures the share of income going to the highest income quintile is 58.3 percent among the least free nations and is 44.4 percent among the most free, a staggering difference of nearly 14.0 percentage points. Among the poorest members of society choice of the rights regime does not have much of an impact on their share of income. While the share averaged across rights measures is larger in the most free nations (5.7 vs. 5.3), the difference is not statistically significant.3

Economic progress and equity are not incompatible. Nations can move to a less restrictive rights regime and increase economic efficiency, economic growth, and equity. Collectivism is a lubricious path to economic progress and equity. Using Ward's composite inequality index, they correlated the Ward measure with GNP per capita, Gastil's rights measures, and a number of other policy and quality of life variables. They found evidence that choice of economic system (capitalism vs. socialism) had no effect on the inequality measure, but that inequality diminishes with increases in civil and political rights.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Adelman, I. and Morris, C.T. (1967). Society, politics, and economic development. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins.

    Google Scholar 

  • Adelman, I. (1973). Economic growth and social equity in developing countries. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ahluwalia, M.S. (1976). Inequality, poverty and development. Journal of Development Economics 34: 307–342.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aigner, D.J. and Chu, S.F. (1968). On estimating the industry production function. American Economic Review 58 (September): 826–839.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aigner, D.J., Lovell, C.A.K. and Schmidt, P. (1977). Formulation and estimation of stochastic production models. Journal of Econometrics (January): 21–37

  • Atkinson, A.T. (1970). On the measurement of inequality. Journal of Economic Theory 2: 244–263.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G. and Buchanan, J.M. (1980). The power to tax: Analytical foundations of a fiscal constitution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J.M. (1975). The limits of liberty. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J.M. and Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chenery, H.B., et al. (1974). Redistribution with growth. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cowell, F. (1977). Measuring inequality. Oxford: Phillip Allan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dempster, A.P., Laird, N.M. and Rubin, D.G. (1977). Maximum likelihood from incomplete data via the em al gorithm. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society Series B 39: 1–38.

    Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper and Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dye, T.R. and Zeigler, H. (1988). Political Science and Politics 21 (1) (Winter): 45–56.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gastil, R.D. (1982). Freedom in the world. Westport, CT: Greenwood.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greene, W.H. (1980). Maximum likelihood estimation of econometric frontier functions. Journal of Econometrics 13: 27–56.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greene, W.H. (1980). The estimation of a flexible frontier production model. Journal of Econometrics 13: 101–115.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huang, C.J. (1984). Estimation of stochastic frontier production function and technical inefficiency via the em algorithm. Southern Economic Journal 50 (3): 847–856.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jain, S. (1975). Size distribution of income. Washington, DC: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, A.O. (1974). The political economy of the rent-seeking society. American Economic Review 64 (June): 291–303.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maitland, F.W. (1968). The constitutional history of England. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Musgrave, R.A. (1959). The theory of public finance. New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Okun, A.M. (1975). Equality and efficiency. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rabushka, A. (1989). Preliminary definition of economic freedom. Mimeo. In Freedom, democracy and economic welfare: Proceedings of an international symposium, 127–157. Vancouver: Fraser Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scully, G.W. (1987). The choice of law and the extent of liberty. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 143: 595–615.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scully, G.W. (1988). The institutional framework and economic development. Journal of Political Economy 96 (June): 652–662.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scully, G.W. (1989). The size of the state, economic growth and the efficient utilization of national resources. Public Choice 63 (2): 149–164.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scully, G.W. and Slottje, D.J. (1989). The paradox of politics and policy in redistributing income. Public Choice 60 (1): 55–70.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scully, G.W. (1989). Measuring economic liberty. Paper prepared for the Liberty Fund-Fraser Institute conference on rating economic freedom, Banff Springs, Alberta, Canada.

  • Stigler, G.J. (1970). Director's law of public income redistribution. Journal of Law and Economics 13 (April): 1–10.

    Google Scholar 

  • Summers, R. and Heston, A. (1984). Improved international comparisons of real product and its composition: 1950–1980. Review of Income and Wealth 30 (June): 207–262.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thiel, H. (1967). Economics and information theory. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1967). The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies and theft. Western Economic Journal 5 (June): 224–232.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1983). Economics of income redistribution. Boston: Kluwer-Nijhoff.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1986). The economics of wealth and poverty. New York: New York University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (1985). World development report: 1985. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Additional information

I thank Robert Klitgaard, Philip Porter, Julian Simon, Dan Slottje, George Stigler, Robert Tollison, and Gordon Tullock for comments on the initial draft of the paper.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Scully, G.W. Rights, equity, and economic efficiency. Public Choice 68, 195–215 (1991). https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00173828

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00173828

Keywords

Navigation